If you watching this video, it's probably because the individual choice model and indifference curves in particular are making your head hurt. Well don't worry. We're going to clear it all up. The first thing to get straight is your graph. In particular the axis of your graph. For simplicity we're trying to model how one individual chooses between two different goods say Burritos and movie tickets. One axis of our graph measures the number of Burritos that person buys, and the other axis measures how many movie tickets they buy. So before we go any further let's remind ourselves that this graph is not the same as supply and demand. Supply and demand has price on the vertical and the quantity of one good on the horizontal. This graph shows quantities of two different goods one on each axis. Moreover, supply and demand is for dozens of producers and millions of consumers. This graph models the decision of one person and let's do a quick recap of XY graphing from high school. On this graph a point represents a particular combination of movie tickets and Burritos. For example, this point represents three movies and five Burritos. While this point represents six movies and two Burritos. The individual choice model uses the same graph that our budget lines did. In this case suppose our theoretical person call her Zoe, has a $180 to spend every month. Movie tickets are $9 while a Burrito is $6. We find our budget line by finding the intercepts. If Zoe spent all $180 on movie tickets she could get 20 tickets per month. On the other hand if she instead spent all $180 on Burritos she could get 30 burritos per month but like most people she is probably more interested in a combination of Burritos and movies. The combinations she can afford are given by the line connecting these intercepts. Remember each one of the points on that line represents a specific combination of Burritos and movies. Let's talk about those combinations for a second. Each combination of Burritos and movies gives Zoe a certain amount of happiness, presumably zero Burritos and zero movies gives her zero enjoyment, but other combinations are tasty and keep her entertained. So she gets some positive quantities of happiness from those. Wait, did we just claim that it's possible to quantify human happiness? Yes of course. We're economists. We do stuff like that all the time, but it's a little cumbersome to keep track of a happiness number for every Burrito-movie combination. So what if we graph those happiness numbers vertically and we don't have to just plot a few points, we can put in the happiness level for every single combination and it would form sort of a surface like this. So what is this thing showing us? For a given amount of Burritos and movie tickets the height of the surface above the graph shows the resulting happiness for Zoe. Now obviously she wants to get as high up on that surface as possible because that will give her the most happiness possible, but to do that we need to be able to measure height. So we zap a bunch of horizontal lines across the surface each at a specific height. The result looks sort of like a contour map or a topographic map. The shape of the lines tells us the shape of the hill. On a contour map all of the points on the same line are, by definition, at the same elevation. In our map of Zoe's brain here all the points on the same line are combinations of Burritos and movies that give Zoe exactly the same amount of happiness. For that reason we'd expect her to be indifferent between two points on the same line. So we call those lines indifference curves. Now in case you only have a two-dimensional notebook instead of a 3D hologram to do your homework, let's just look straight down on this happiness map, sort of like a drone looking straight down on an actual hill. We can focus just on those contour lines. Why do we need these to help Zoe find the highest point? Well compare point A which is one combination of Burritos and movies and point B which is another combination. She has more movies and more Burritos at combination B. So it's obvious that she prefers B to A but what about combination C, that has way more movies than combinations A or B but also fewer Burritos than both. Here's where we really need our indifference curves. They tell us the obvious that B is farther up the hill than A so she's happier at B than at A but the indifference curves allow us to see that for Zoe anyway, combination C is preferred to A but B is better than C. We wouldn't have known that without these indifference curves. What's to keep Zoe from going further and further up the hill to higher and higher levels of happiness, remember, each point on this plane is a combination of Burritos and movie tickets. At point B, for example, she's buying 10 movie tickets and 20 Burritos per month but at $9 for movie tickets and $6 for Burritos that comes to $210 which is more money than she has. So the budget line we drew a few minutes ago effectively becomes a fence running across the hill. Zoe's goal becomes getting as high on the hill as possible while staying inside the fence. She would love to consume combinations on the other side of the fence like point B, but she can't afford it. Likewise, it doesn't make sense for her to buy less than she can afford. That would put her lower down the hill than the fence. If she wants to get as high up on the hill and stay inside the fence that is if she wants to get the most happiness from her purchases but can't exceed her budget, then it makes sense that she'll pick a spot right up against the fence. The question is where. Well she could pick this point but she could be higher on the hill and still stay on her side of the fence if she moved this way. Likewise, here's another point that's up against the fence but it's lower than it could be. Her solution is to find the one point where an indifference curve just barely touches the fence, the point at which her indifference curve is tangent to the budget line. That's the highest point she can find. Great! So how does she literally make that point happen? Again every point on this plane is a combination of Burritos and movie tickets. So in this example she buys six movie tickets and 21 Burritos per month. That comes to $180 and gives her the highest happiness possible given her budget. In short, consumers maximize their happiness which we call utility by finding the point where their budget line is just tangent to an indifference curve. Then they make that point happen by buying that specific combination of the two goods.