We've talked about long-run potential GDP and we've also talked about the aggregate supply and aggregate demand model. Today we're going to put them together to talk about business cycles. How can we show the relationship between actual and potential GDP? One way is on our aggregate supply, aggregate demand graph. Recall that the horizontal axis is real GDP which we sometimes refer to as output or Y. Potential GDP shows up in this graph as a vertical line often called Y star or the long-run aggregate supply curve. Why is it vertical? Remember that the vertical axis is the economy-wide price level. The LRAS is vertical because the price level can change all over the place but potential GDP stays the same. That's because it's determined by labor force, capital stock, and productivity, not the price level. Then we put in aggregate demand and a short-run aggregate supply. As we've seen their intersection gives us the actual GDP at any given point in time. Another way we can compare actual and potential GDP is on a time graph. Here the horizontal axis is years and the vertical axis is the economy's total output and income. Potential GDP is determined by capital stock, labor force, and productivity. Those factors change slowly over time. So potential GDP tends to grow gradually. At any given time actual GDP may be above or below potential GDP. Starting with actual output equal to potential, let's look at what happens if there's a negative shock to aggregate demand. For some reason suppose that households decide to spend less on consumption or businesses spend less on investment. In the aggregate demand aggregate supply model aggregate demand shifts inwards. Actual GDP falls below potential GDP; the LRAS. Meanwhile, on our time graph actual GDP falls below the trend line of potential GDP. Although these graphs are showing the same thing, we call the situation where actual output is below potential, a recessionary gap. In this situation some workers are unemployed, some capital like factories or stores are vacant. In real life this describes what happened to the economy after the financial crisis of 2008. Consumer spending and business investment fell shifting aggregate demand inwards and producing a large recessionary gap. As discussed in other videos, there are different ways for an economy to get out of a recessionary gap. The government may implement expansionary, monetary, or fiscal policy. This would boost aggregate demand back out, raising actual output back to potential. In many models output will also return to potential on its own if you wait long enough. Unemployed workers and capital drive down production costs which show up as an outward shift in the short-run aggregate supply. The move along on aggregate demand returns output to potential. In either scenario the time graph shows actual output climbing back towards the potential trend. Starting with actual output equal to potential, let's now look at what happens if there is a positive shock to aggregate demand. For some reason suppose that households decide to spend more on consumption or businesses spend more on investment. In the aggregate demand aggregate supply model, aggregate demand shifts outwards, actual GDP rises above potential GDP; the LRAS. Meanwhile, on our time graph actual GDP rises above the trend line of potential GDP. Both graphs are showing the same thing. We call the situation where actual output is above potential, an inflationary gap. In this situation businesses are employing all the workers in capital they can get their hands on to produce the highest possible output. In real life this describes what happened to the economy during the 1960's; a combination of consumer and government spending boosted aggregate demand raising output and resulting in inflation at the end of the decade. As discussed in other videos there are different ways for an economy to get out of an inflationary gap. The government may implement contractionary, monetary, or fiscal policy. This would pull aggregate demand back in lowering output back to potential. In many models output will also return to potential on its own if you wait long enough. A bidding war among employers will raise wages and resource costs which shows up as an inward shift in the short-run aggregate supply. The move along on aggregate demand returns output to potential. In either scenario the time graph shows actual output falling back towards the potential trend.